TransWikia.com

Power Options & Forwards on Stock Squared

Quantitative Finance Asked on December 28, 2021

Short story: the process for Stock price squared is not a martingale when discounted by the money-market numeraire under the risk-neutral measure. How can we then compute derivative prices on $S_t^2$ under the risk neutral measure? Wouldn’t this lead to arbitrage?

Long story: I found some great posts on power options, for example Finding price of the power option. Whilst the maths is clear, I am still somewhat confused about the concept: starting with a simple option on Stock price squared, I do not fully comprehend how an optional claim can be priced within the regular B-S framework, when the price process for $S_t^2=S_0^2exp((2r-sigma^2)t+2sigma W_t)$ is not a martingale when discounted by $e^{rt}$ under the risk-neutral money-market numeraire.

I consider a single period model with zero rates. As outlined in the post What is the Risk Neutral Measure?, in the one-period model, the risk-neutral measure arises from no arbitrage assumption in the model. We assume that initially, the stock price is $S_0$ and after one period it can be either $S_u=S_0*u$ or $S_d=S_0*d$, with $u$ and $d$ being some multiplicative factors. Pricing a derivative claim with pay-off function $V(.)$ on the underlying stock $S_t$ via replication gives rise to:

$$V_0 = left(V(S_u) left( frac{1 -d}{u-d} right) + V(S_d) left(frac{u-1}{u-d} right) right)$$

Imposing $u leq 1 leq d$ will ensure that there is no arbitrage in the one-period model. Furthermore, as a consequence of the condition $u leq 1 leq d$, we get that $0 leq frac{1 -d}{u-d} leq 1$ and $0 leq frac{u-1}{u-d} leq 1$. Therefore, we can define $p_u:=frac{1 -d}{u-d}$, $p_d:=frac{u-1}{u-d}$ and we can call $p_u$ and $p_d$ "probabilities": indeed, in the one-period model, $p_u$ & $p_d$ form the discrete (risk-neutral) probability measure.

Now, the interesting point is that pricing the claim $V(.)$ on $S_t^2$ via replication in the one-period model actually leads to a different probability measure:

(i) Upper state: $S_{t_1}^2=S_0^2u^2$, denoting risk-free bond as $B$ we have $B_{t_1}=B_{t_0}=1$ since rates are zero and the option pay-off is $V_u=V((S_0u)^2)=[S_0^2u^2-K]^+$.

(ii) Lower state: $S_{t_1}^2=S_0^2d^2$, $B_{t_1}=B_{t_0}=1$, $V_d=V((S_0d)^2)=[S_0^2d^2-K]^+$.

Trying to replicate the payoff $V(S_{t_1}^2)$ in both states via the underlying stock and the risk-free bond, we get two equations with two unknowns (x = number of stocks, y = number of bonds I wanna hold to replicate option pay-off):

$$(i) V_u=x*S_0^2u^2+y*1$$

$$(ii) V_d=x*S_0^2d^2+y*1$$

Solving the system of equations yields:

$$ x=frac{V_u-V_d}{S_0^2(u^2-d^2)}, y=frac{u^2V_d-d^2V_u}{u^2-d^2}$$

Which then gives the claim price as (after some basic algebraic simplifications):

$$V_0=x*S_0^2+y*1=V_u*frac{1-d^2}{u^2-d^2}+V_dfrac{u^2-1}{u^2-d^2}$$

Setting $p_u^*:=frac{1-d^2}{u^2-d^2}$ and $p_d^*:=frac{u^2-1}{u^2-d^2}$, the above can be re-written as:

$$V_0=V_up_u^*+V_dp_d^*=mathbb{E}^{Q_2}[V_{t_1}]$$

In other words, the replication argument gives rise to some new probability measure where $p_u^*=frac{1-d^2}{u^2-d^2}neq p_u=frac{1-d}{u-d}$ and $p_d^*=frac{u^2-1}{u^2-d^2}neq p_d=frac{1-d}{u-d}$.

Instead, we actually have that $p_u^*=p_u frac{1+d}{u+d}$ and $p_d^*=p_d frac{1+u}{u+d}$.

Question: So going back to the the start and considering the thread Finding price of the power option, how come we can price power options under the B-S classical risk-neutral measure? That would be equivalent to saying that under the one period model (with rates being zero), the price of the claim $V(S^2_t)$ could be computed as $V_0=mathbb{E}^Q[V_t(S_t^2)]=p_uV_u(S_t^2) + p_dV_d(S_t^2)$, which does not produce the correct result (indeed, above we instead get that $V_0=mathbb{E}^{Q_2}[V_t(S_t^2)]=p_u^*V_u(S_t^2) + p_d^*V_d(S_t^2)$).

One Answer

Consider a financial market with a filtered probability space $left(Omega,mathcal{F},(mathcal{F}_t),mathbb Pright)$ satisfying usual conditions equipped with a stock price process $S_t$. Suppose there exists a risk-free asset who is governed by $mathrm{d}B_t=r_tB_tmathrm{d}t$.

Suppose the market is free of arbitrage, i.e. there exists a probability measure $mathbb Qsimmathbb P$ such that $$ mathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{S_{t}}{B_{t}}Bigg|mathcal{F}_sright]=frac{S_s}{B_s}$$ for $sleq t$.

Let $xi$ be an integrable and $mathcal{F}_T$-measurable random variable representing the time-$T$ payoff of some claim (contract). It's typically a function of the terminal stock price $S_T$. What's the fair (i.e. arbitrage-free) time-$t$ price for such a claim? Let's study the following value (or price) process $$V_t=B_tmathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{xi}{B_T}bigg|mathcal{F}_tright].$$ So intuitively, the fair price of a contract $xi$ equals the expected discounted payoff expressed in terms of the numéraire ($B_t$). Of course, $V_T=xi$, thus $V_t$ replicates the payoff $xi$. If interest rates are deterministic, we can pull $B_T$ out of the expectation.

The discounted value process, $frac{V_t}{B_t}$, is a $mathbb{Q}$-martingale by construction. It follows immediately from the tower law. We simply note that $$mathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{V_t}{B_t}bigg|mathcal{F}_sright]=mathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[mathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{xi}{B_T}bigg|mathcal{F}_tright]bigg|mathcal{F}_sright]=mathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{xi}{B_T}bigg|mathcal{F}_sright]=frac{V_s}{B_s}.$$ In general, if $X$ is an integrable random variable, then $M_t=mathbb{E}[X|mathcal{F}_t]$ is a martingale.

Now the catch: the augmented market (with stock, bond and value process) consists of assets whose discounted values are martingales. Thus, by using the first FTAP, we know the market remains free of arbitrage and $V_t$ is a way of replicating $xi$ without creating an arbitrage opportunity.

If there exists a perfect hedge for $xi$ (which is self-financing), then $V_t$ has the same price as this perfect hedge for every time point $tleq T$ (law of one price). Thus, the value process is in fact independent of the equivalent martingale measure (if several exist) for replicable payoffs (this, by the way, points to the second FTAP). In fact, for every equivalent martingale measure $mathbb Q$, the map $ximapsto B_tmathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{xi}{B_T}bigg|mathcal{F}_tright]$ defines a linear pricing functional.

Example: pricing an asset paying $xi=S_T^2$ under constant interest rates and geometric Brownian motion dynamics (without dividends). The answer is simply $$V_t=B_tmathbb{E}^mathbb{Q}left[frac{xi}{B_T}bigg|mathcal{F}_tright]=S_t^2e^{(r+sigma^2)(T-t)}.$$ Details to this calculation are in the comments. This formula makes intuitive sense: after a numeraire change, $V_t$ is just the expected value of the stock price under the stock measure under which the stock price grows at the drift rate $r+sigma^2$. Importantly, this price is model-dependent. A standard forward paying $S_T$ is model-independent (and follows from the definition of the equivalent martingale measure). Also, the price of a power claim paying $S_T^2$ is not just delta one but has volatility exposure.


In a one period, binomial setting, the stock moves from $S_0$ to either $S_0u$ or $S_0d$. A hedging portfolio invests $Delta$ in the stock and $M$ in the bond, i.e. $Pi_0=Delta S_0+MB$ and $Pi_T=Delta S_T+M$ (in your notation, $x=Delta$ and $y=M$). You try to replicate a general payoff $V$. Then, solve begin{align*} begin{cases} V_u = S_uDelta+M, \ V_d = S_dDelta+M. end{cases} end{align*} Solving this system leads to a discrete analogue of a delta hedge: begin{align*} Delta &= frac{V_u-V_d}{S_u-S_d}, \ M &= frac{uV_u+dV_d}{u-d}. end{align*} Thus, $$ Pi_0=Delta S_0+MB=frac{V_u-V_d}{S_u-S_d}S_0+frac{uV_u+dV_d}{u-d}B=frac{1-Bd}{u-d}V_u+frac{Bu-1}{u-d}V_d.$$ You see, the probabilities are independent of the payoffs $V_u$ and $V_d$. Now, simply set $V_u=S_0^2u^2$ and $V_d=S_0^2d^2$ and you're done.

Answered by Kevin on December 28, 2021

Add your own answers!

Ask a Question

Get help from others!

© 2024 TransWikia.com. All rights reserved. Sites we Love: PCI Database, UKBizDB, Menu Kuliner, Sharing RPP