Economics Asked by Gang'sBigBoss on July 12, 2021
Assume the relation $succeq$ is continuous (by the preferential definition). Does this mean the graph of Indifference Curves are continuous?
Since $sim$ satisfies the definition for $succeq$, we have the IC follow the preferential definition. But what about the topological definition?
I think it does, and here’s what I have done. Please verify!
Rephrasing the question: Given $I = {x : x sim y}$ equipped with the standard topology, consider $f : I to mathbb{R}^n$ such that $f(x) = x$. How do you show $f$ is continuous? (Note. I don’t know if it is true, I have assumed it to be true and tried to show that it indeed is.)
Proof. An arbitrary $S subseteq I$ when closed does not violate the continuity, so for any other $S$ which is open, $f^{-1}(S) = S$ is open. $blacksquare$.
To follow up on the answer of @VARulle let me give you some conditions for which the indifference curve is path connected.
The argument can also be found in the book Mathematical Methods and Models for Economists by Angel de la Fuente.
Preferences are monotone if $x > y$ implies $x succ y$ and that preferences are continuous if $x_n succeq y_n$, $x_n to x$ and $y_n to y$ imply $x succeq y$.
Let us limit ourselves to the space $mathbb{R}^n_{++}$ of strictly positive bundles. For some $a in mathbb{R}^n_{++}$ consider the indifference curve $I(a) = {x in mathbb{R}^n_{++}| x sim a}$.
Theorem If preferences are monotone and continuous then for $a in mathbb{R}^n_{++}$, the set $I(a)$ is path-connected.
As being path-connected is a topological property, it suffices to show that there is a homeomorphism between $I(a)$ and a path-connected set. For this, we will take the set $Delta$: $$ Delta = {z in mathbb{R}^n_{++}: sum_i z_i = 1} $$ This set is path-connected as any two elements in $Delta$ can be connected by the line segment that has these points as endpoints.
Consider the radial projection function $f: I(a) to Delta$ defined as: $$ f(x) = dfrac{x}{sum_i x_i} $$ As we restrict ourselves to $mathbb{R}^n_{++}$, the function $f$ is well defined. It is easy to see that $f$ is continuous. To show that it is a homeomorphism, we have to show that it is a bijection and that $f^{-1}$ is also continuous.
First, to show that $f$ is onto. let $z in Delta$ and consider the ray $alpha z$ with $alpha > 0$. Then for $alpha$ large enough, we have $alpha z > a$, so by monotonicity $alpha z succ a$. Also for $alpha > 0$ small enough, we have $alpha z < a$ so, by monotonicity, $a succ alpha z$.
Let $alpha^ast = inf {alpha| alpha z succ a}$ which is well defined by the argument above. Then by continuity $alpha^ast z succeq a$. Also for all $alpha < alpha^ast$ we have $a succeq alpha z$ so again by continuity $a succeq alpha^ast z$. This shows that $alpha^ast z sim a$ or equivalently $alpha^ast z in I(a)$. Defining $x = alpha^ast z$, gives that $x sim a$ and $h(x) = z$, so $h$ is onto.
To show that $f$ is a bijection, let $f(x) = f(y) = z$. We need to show that $x = y$. We have: $$ dfrac{x}{sum_i x_i} = dfrac{y}{sum_i y_i} = z. $$ As such, $$ x sum_i y_i = y sum_i x_i, $$ which shows that $x$ and $y$ are proportional to each other, i.e., $$ alpha x = beta y. $$ if $alpha = beta$ then $x$ and $y$ are identical, so either $alpha > beta$ or vice versa. But then by monotonicity $y succ frac{beta}{alpha} y = x$ or vice versa, which gives a contradiction with $x, y in I(a)$.
Finally, to see that $f^{-1}$ is continuous, let $z in Delta$ and take any sequence $z_n to z$. It suffices to show the existence of a subsequence $z_{k_n}$ such that $h^{-1}(z_{k_n}) to h^{-1}(z)$.
Define $x_n = h^{-1}(z_n)$ and $x = h^{-1}(z)$. Then: $$ alpha_n x_n = z_n. $$ with $alpha_n = frac{1}{sum_i x_{i,n}}$ also we have that: $$ alpha x = z, $$ with $alpha = frac{1}{sum_i x_i}$. It suffices to show that there is a subsequence for which $x_{k_n} to x$.
If ${alpha_n}$ is bounded, there is a convergent subsequence $alpha_{k_n} to alpha^ast$. If $alpha^ast = 0$ then as $z_n to z$ there is an $n_k$ large enough such that $x_{n_k} = frac{z_{n_k}}{alpha_{n_k}} > frac{z}{alpha} = x$ which would contradict $x_{n_k} sim x$. As such, $alpha^ast > 0$ and: $$ x_{k_n} = frac{z_{k_n}}{alpha_{k_n}} to frac{z}{alpha^ast} = frac{alpha}{alpha^ast} x. $$ Then as $x_{k_n} sim x$ for all $n$, by continuity, $x sim frac{alpha}{alpha^ast}x$ which can only hold (by monotonicity) if $alpha^ast = alpha$. This shows that $x_n to x$.
If $alpha_n > 0$ is unbounded, then there is a subsequence $alpha_{k_n} to infty$. Then along this subsequence (as $z_{k_n} to z$) we have $$ x_{k_n} = frac{z_{k_n}}{alpha_{k_n}} to 0, $$ So for $n$ large enough $x_{k_n} < x$ which means that $x succ x_{k_n}$ which again contradicts $x_{k_n} sim x$. This shows that $f^{-1}$ is continuous $square$.
Correct answer by tdm on July 12, 2021
Given your last comment above it seems that what you are really asking is whether the indifference sets of a continuous preference relation on $mathbb R^n_+$ are path-connected. The answer is No. Let $n=1$ and let the preference relation be represented by $u(x)=(1-x)^2$. Then the indifference set e.g. for $u=1$ is ${0}cup{2}$, which is not path-connected.
Answered by VARulle on July 12, 2021
Get help from others!
Recent Answers
Recent Questions
© 2024 TransWikia.com. All rights reserved. Sites we Love: PCI Database, UKBizDB, Menu Kuliner, Sharing RPP